My last permanent position was in the mid-1990s. Since then my positions have all been temporary contracts of various tenure. To a large extent, my situation has been the outcome of personal decisions and circumstances. But it has given me an insight into the nature of the casual labour market.
Peter Lyons: Casualised labour no production panacea
Subscribe to listen
The economic ideal of a highly mobile, flexible workforce would have dire consequences for social cohesion. It would foster a nation of economic transients with few permanent social ties beyond immediate family.
One of the interesting aspects of the greater flexibility in our labour market over the past 20 years has been that labour productivity has not increased dramatically as a result. Despite the reduction in union power and increased ease of hiring and firing this does not appear to have led to major improvements in the efficiency of the average worker.
In 1914, Henry Ford introduced the $5 daily wage into his car factories. This wage was twice the going rate. Some commentators believed this move was to allow his workers to buy the cars they were producing. It is now recognised that it was designed to improve labour productivity in his factories.
It was to ensure that Ford would have the pick of candidates eager to work for such a high wage. The result was reduced absenteeism, low staff turnover and fewer resources needed for staff training. It led to major immediate improvements in productivity.
Ford had intuitively recognised a key feature of the labour market. People are not tradeable commodities like bananas or onions or cabbages. If you treat people like units of labour they will respond accordingly and productivity will suffer.
The relationship between an employer and employee is entirely different from the relationship between buyers and sellers in other markets. It is encapsulated in the saying, "You pay peanuts, you get monkeys." It could be extended to include "treat people like cabbages and they go rotten on you".
If people feel they are being treated fairly and as individuals they will respond accordingly. If people feel they are being treated as disposable units of labour then outcomes will suffer. This may help explain why the growth in labour productivity in New Zealand over the past few decades has been less than spectacular despite significant reforms aimed at increasing labour market flexibility.
This time each year, I have a short interview with my principal. He often starts with a discourse on the state of the New Zealand economy. He then asks what I think is likely to happen to the housing market as he owns several properties. I assure him that the market can only continue to climb. He smiles appreciatively and offers me another contract. As long as the housing market holds up this arrangement works well for both of us.
• Peter Lyons teaches economics at St Peters College in Epsom and has written several economics texts.