Geof Shirtcliffe: Executive pay may be caught in an upward spiral

11 comments
The boss has always earned a multiple of what the average worker earns. Photo / Kenny Rodger
The boss has always earned a multiple of what the average worker earns. Photo / Kenny Rodger

It is an article of faith lying at the core of corporate and securities law that, as the American jurist Louis Brandeis famously observed, "sunlight is the best disinfectant".

Securities offering documents must disclose all material matters, financial advisers must disclose commissions - and companies must disclose senior executive's remuneration.

But is our faith misplaced? In the case of executive remuneration disclosure, perhaps. The boss has always earned a multiple of what the average worker earns. But over the past 15 years, that multiple has increased. A recent survey estimates that NZX-listed companies now pay their CEOs an average 18 times what they pay the average worker.

If this seems a lot, it pales into insignificance compared with other countries. In the Financial Times ("It's time to name and shame the corporate scroungers", August 1) Neil Stephens points out that the multiplier for FTSE 100 companies has risen from 47 in 1998 to 120 last year.

Stephens is concerned at the potentially corrosive effects of a widespread perception that the only "winners" are a privileged few at the top. He is not alone in this. Concerns about what Robert Frank and Philip Cook have dubbed a "winner take all" society are heard across the political spectrum.

Neither is Stephens alone in suggesting that part of the answer is more and better disclosure - witness Brian Gaynor's reported comments last weekend on New Zealand's failure to require a sufficient breakdown of CEO remuneration.

But are such calls right? Will "greater transparency" bring allegedly avaricious captains of industry to heel? Or might it, in fact, have the opposite effect?

Numerous jurisdictions (including New Zealand) require senior executive remuneration to be disclosed, at least by public listed companies. So everyone knows what everyone else is paid. This might ratchet up executive remuneration in a number of ways.

First, few chief executives will wish to be paid less than other comparable chief executives. And many companies will share that reluctance - their boards understandably fearful that they will be unable to attract the calibre of individual they require, or that the company itself will be perceived to be below average.

But if both sides of the negotiation are pre-disposed to pay at least the average - and preferably more than average - then the upward march of remuneration is guaranteed: each time remuneration is re-set, the (previous) average becomes the floor, making the (new) average higher, thereby raising the floor for the next re-set, and so on, leading to what economists Michael Faulkender and Jun Yang, in a study of Canadian executive remuneration, called the "Lake Wobegon effect" (after Garrison Keillor's mythical home town of Lake Wobegon, where all the children are above average).

Secondly, and more speculatively, increased availability of information on income and wealth leads to increased publicity on income and wealth. (How many people have never shown any interest in the Rich List?)

Might this, in turn, increase the relative importance to executives of income and wealth as markers of success, and the relative acceptance by boards of increased senior executive remuneration?

Thirdly, and more speculatively still, might greater publicity on executive remuneration generally, and a company's executive remuneration in particular, make the board unconsciously less reticent about approving even higher incomes in future, because the disclosure requirement in some way gives them greater "licence" to do so?

Clearly this is speculative. It simply may not be possible to disentangle the effects of compulsory remuneration disclosure from those of other powerful forces leading to "winner take all" markets for talent.

And even if compulsory disclosure is shown to increase executive remuneration, this is a genie which may long since have smashed the bottle from which it escaped.

But if there are any graduate students out there with an interest in the law of unintended consequences, I've got a suggestion for a research project.

Geof Shirtcliffe is a partner in Chapman Tripp. Ideas expressed here are his own and are not necessarily shared by the firm or its clients.

- NZ Herald

Have your say

We aim to have healthy debate. But we won't publish comments that abuse others. View commenting guidelines.

1200 characters left

Sort by
  • Oldest

© Copyright 2014, APN New Zealand Limited

Assembled by: (static) on production bpcf05 at 24 Oct 2014 06:40:58 Processing Time: 412ms